It is no secret that talent is the most
important driver of growth in the 21st century and that talented people are
essential to innovation (Kepner, 2008, p. 62). Particularly in an era of rapid
globalization where most financial assets tend to move freely around the world,
while the mobility of human capital lags behind.
In that sense, the case of the United
States is quite alarming. There is a growing demand for high-skilled workers,
while the quality and supply of education are not improving at the same pace,
resulting in a sharp rise in the inequality of wages (Autor, 2010, p. 1). Also,
there are increasing job openings in both high-skill, high-wage professions,
and low-skilled, low-wage positions, while employment possibilities are
diminishing in both middle-skill, white collar administrative, and sales
occupations, and in middle-skill, blue-collar manual jobs (Autor, 2010, p. 1).
Additionally, jobs creation is occurring further away from where people live,
especially the poorer population, limiting their possibilities for job search,
particularly while unemployed (Kneebone & Holmes, 2015, p. 9).
However, cities are the right places to
tackle this vicious circle of a diminishing supply of skilled workers,
companies moving to different locations, unemployment, weak tax collection,
inadequate school systems, low supply of skilled labor, and so on.
First of all, in the short term, cities
with increasing unemployment need to strengthen programs to improve the
technical skills of individuals finishing high-school (Kepner, 2008, p. 76).
Additionally, cities can promote, through tax rebates, that local firms invest
more on on-the-job training, very much in a similar way that South Korean
cities did (Pagés, 2014). This case is interesting because the government helped
firms develop training cooperatives for small and medium enterprises, that
increased the skills of the workers along the added-value curve.
Second, in the long-term, cities should
invest in early childhood education, as well as the quality of their colleges,
paying close attention to the human capital that firms need now, as well as in
the future (Kepner, 2008, pp. 71-84).
Finally, cities should promote that their
young professionals stay. One way to do this is by fostering entrepreneurship
with matching grants or by facilitating the connection with private investors
(Kepner, 2008, p. 82).
However, cities must also pay close
attention to the automation paradox. As Rotman (2013) illustrates,
"technological progress is eliminating the need for many types of jobs and
leaving the typical worker worse off than before." In that sense, cities
must implement technology watch programs to be aware of technological changes
taking place, so that they can act accordingly.
Sources
Autor. D. (2010). The polarization of job
opportunities in the U.S. labor market. Retrieved from: https://learn.bu.edu/bbcswebdav/pid-4374104-dt-content-rid-15118042_1/courses/16fallmetua704_d1/The%20Polarization%20of%20Jobs.pdf
Kepner, R. (2008). The talent imperative
of Older Industrial Areas. The American
Assembly.
Kneebone, E., & Holmes, N. (2015). The
growing distance between people and jobs in metropolitan America. Metropolitan Policy Program. Brookings
Institute.
Pagés, Carmen (2014). El ejemplo de Corea: tres claves para emular
al tigre. IADB. Retrieved from: http://blogs.iadb.org/trabajo/2014/05/15/el-ejemplo-de-corea-tres-claves-para-emular-al-tigre/
Rotman, D. (2013, June 12). How technology is destroying jobs. MIT Technology Review. Retrieved from https://www.technologyreview.com/s/515926/how-technology-is-destroying-jobs/
Rotman, D. (2013, June 12). How technology is destroying jobs. MIT Technology Review. Retrieved from https://www.technologyreview.com/s/515926/how-technology-is-destroying-jobs/
No hay comentarios.:
Publicar un comentario